menu
close

Author(s):

Andrea Ferrero | University of Oxford
Maurizio Michael Habib | European Central Bank (ECB)
Livio Stracca | European Central Bank (ECB)
Fabrizio Venditti | Bank of Italy

Keywords:

Global Financial Cycle , monetary policy , macro-prudential policies , foreign-exchange intervention , capital controls , emerging markets , institutions

JEL Codes:

F32 , F38 , E52 , G28

The views expressed belong to the authors and are not necessarily shared by the institutions to which they are affiliated.

Taming the global financial cycle has become a pressing concern for emerging market economies that want to avoid the vagaries of swings in capital flows. Our work shoes that strong institutions play a key role in shaping the impact of global financial shocks on emerging markets, the response of counter-cyclical policies and their effectiveness. Emerging markets may invest in ex ante costly structural reforms that raise institutional strength and shield their economy from shifts in global financial conditions or may decide to avoid these costs and rely only on ex post cyclical policies, remaining though less insulated from global shocks.

Introduction

Taming the global financial cycle has become a pressing concern for emerging market economies (EMEs). Global financial markets are a crucial source of funding for EMEs, but financial globalization has boosted the international diversification of portfolios and has led to an increasing correlation of risky asset prices across markets, driven by shifts in risk aversion (Ward et al., 2018) and US monetary policy (Rey, 2013; Miranda-Agrippino and Rey, 2021).
Policymakers in EMEs, therefore, face a difficult trade-off between domestic and external stabilization. On the one hand, their policies should ensure that their countries reap the benefits of capital mobility. On the other, authorities need to shield their domestic financing conditions and hence their economies from sudden swings in capital flows and in asset valuations driven by global factors. The menu of available policies to lean against the global financial cycle is large, but their use and effectiveness varies across countries and over time (Mano and Sgherri, 2020).
In our work (Ferrero et al., 2022) we show empirically that the quality of institutions (e.g., the Rule of Law) and its relationship with counter-cyclical policies (macroprudential policies, capital controls, monetary policy, and foreign exchange interventions) play a key role in shaping the economic and financial effects of shocks to global financial conditions on EMEs. These results pose an interesting dilemma. EMEs may decide to undertake ex ante costly structural reforms that strengthen institutions and shield their economy from shifts in global financial conditions. Alternatively, EMEs may decide to avoid these costs and rely only on ex post counter-cyclical policies, remaining though less insulated from global shocks when international financial conditions deteriorate.  We use a theoretical model to investigate this issue. The model indicates that structural reforms and counter-cyclical policies are to a large extent substitutes, i.e. countries for which countercyclical policies are (ex post) relatively more effective have less of an incentive in strengthening their institutional framework ex ante.

The empirical analysis

We analyse in a panel model setting the response of the stock market, bond spreads and GDP to global financial shocks in 22 EMEs between 1995 and 2022, ranking countries according to the Worldwide Governance Indicators developed by the World Bank. Two clear and important results emerge from this study:
  • First, negative global financial shocks are less harmful for countries with more solid institutions. Figure 1 illustrates this point for a specific measure of institutional quality, the Rule of Law, by plotting the response to a global financial shock of equity prices, sovereign spreads, and economic activity for two groups of countries with respectively low and high Rule of Law1: the decline in share prices and economic activity and the increase in spreads are relatively smaller in countries with higher Rule of Law.
Figure 1: Economic outcomes, global financial conditions and the Rule of Law
 width=
  • Second, following a negative global financial shock, economies with more solid institutions loosen monetary policy to mitigate the negative effects on the economy and do not deplete foreign exchange reserves. Conversely, in countries where institutions are relatively weaker, policymakers are forced to raise interest rates and intervene in the foreign exchange market (Figure 2), in an attempt to curb the depreciation of the exchange rate and the flight of foreign capital, ultimately further tightening local financial conditions.

Figure 2: Policy response to global financial conditions and the Rule of Law
 width=

These results chime with the findings of Kalemli-Ozcan (2019) that risk perceptions of global investors, the institutional framework and macroeconomic policies are tightly intertwined in EMEs. Her conjecture is that, in countries with low credibility, macroeconomic policies may adversely affect the risk perception of global investors and lead to self-defeating outcomes. Our empirical work largely confirms this intuition.

The model

The above results pose a dilemma for EMEs. Indeed, they could shield their economies from the global financial cycle by making a costly investment ex-ante in strengthening their institutions. Alternatively, they could choose to remain exposed to global financial shocks and to rely only on ex post counter-cyclical policies to steer domestic financial conditions.
A stylized model of a typical debt-constrained EME sheds light on this trade-off. The private sector in the economy can borrow in both domestic and foreign currency, subject to a collateral constraint that depends on the value of the endowment. Since purchasing power parity does not hold, fluctuations in the real exchange rate affect the value of collateral and give rise to a pecuniary externality. In “normal times”, the collateral constraint is slack and the EME enjoys macroeconomic stability. A “crisis” corresponds to a state of the world in which international investors lose confidence in the ability of the EME to repay its debt and the collateral constraint suddenly becomes binding. Because a share of debt is in foreign currency (which recalls the literature on the “original sin”) and the EME real exchange rate depreciates after a global financial shock, the country’s borrowing capacity is further eroded.
Improving domestic institutions (ex ante) makes international investors more willing to accept debt denominated in domestic currency, and thus limits the negative effect of a real exchange rate depreciation on the amount of borrowing in a crisis. The EME can achieve a similar outcome by intervening (ex post) in the foreign exchange market during a crisis to sustain the domestic currency. The model thus shows that structural and counter-cyclical policies are substitutes. As a result, countries for which countercyclical policies are relatively more effective ex post are likely to have less incentives to strengthen their institutional framework ex ante. An interesting extension of our work would be to rationalize the advice, contained for example in the IMF Institutional View, that strengthening institutions should have higher priority compared with applying ex post counter-cyclical policies.

Conclusions

The quality of institutions plays a key role in insulating domestic financial conditions from the global financial cycle in EMEs. Countries with a more solid institutional framework experience a milder tightening of financial conditions in response to a negative global financial shock, and mitigate the impact of external shocks through monetary policy accommodation. A theoretical model indicates that structural and counter-cyclical policies are substitutes. EMEs for which counter-cyclical policies are ex-post relatively more effective have lower incentives in investing ex-ante in structural reforms that may strengthen their institutional framework.

References

Ferrero A., Habib, M., Stracca, L. and F. Venditti (2022): “Leaning against the global financial cycle”, ECB Working paper 2763.
Mano R. C. and S. Sgherri (2020): “One shock, many policy responses”, IMF working paper No. 20/10, January.
Miranda-Agrippino, S., and H. Rey (2020): “U.S. Monetary Policy and the Global Financial Cycle,” Review of Economic Studies, 87(6), 2754–2776.
Rey, H. (2013): “Dilemma not trilemma: the global cycle and monetary policy independence,” Proceedings – Economic Policy Symposium – Jackson Hole, pp. 1–2.
Jordà, Ò., Schularick, M., Taylor, A.M. et al. Global Financial Cycles and Risk Premiums. IMF Econ Rev 67, 109–150 (2019). https://doi.org/10.1057/s41308-019-00077-1
Kalemli-Ozcan, S. (2019): “US Monetary Policy and International Risk Spillovers,” CEPR Discussion Papers 14053, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.
  • 1.

    Countries with a low (high) Rule of Law are those scoring in the first (last) decile of the sample distribution of the Rule of Law indicator.

About the authors

Andrea Ferrero

Andrea Ferrero is a Professor of Economics in the Department of Economics at the University of Oxford and the Levine Senior Research Fellow in Economics at Trinity College Oxford. He holds a BA in Economics from Bocconi University, an MSc in Economics from Universitat Pompeu Fabra, and a Phd in Economics from New York University. Before joining Oxford in September 2013, Andrea spent seven years in the Research Department at the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. He is currently an academic consultant for the Bank of England and the Bank of Finland. His research interests are in the areas of Monetary Economics and International Macroeconomics and his research has appeared in top professional outlets, including the American Economic Review, the Review of Economic Studies, the Economic Journal, and the Journal of Monetary Economics.

Maurizio Michael Habib

Maurizio Michael Habib is Team Lead Economist at the European Central Bank (ECB). His research focuses on international macroeconomic and financial issues, exchange rates, the global financial cycle and global safe assets. He previously worked at the European Commission in Brussels and holds a MSc in economics from Birkbeck College in London and a Ph.D. in economics from the University of Rome “La Sapienza”.

Livio Stracca

Livio Stracca is the Deputy Director General Financial Stability at the European Central Bank and an adjunct Professor at the University of Frankfurt J.-W. Goethe. He has a PhD in Economics and a postgraduate degree in European Union Law. His research interests are mainly in international macroeconomics and monetary economics.

Fabrizio Venditti

Fabrizio Venditti is Head of the Advanced Economies and International Finance Division in the Directorate International Relations and Economics at the Bank of Italy. His research focuses on econometrics, the global financial cycle, commodity markets and forecasting. He holds an MPhil in economics from Oxford University and a Ph.D. in economics from Queen Mary University of London.

More on these topics

Tags: